Although FHA Single Family Mortgage Loan Sale #2 was very successful, a number of issues were raised during and following the sale, in post-sale discussions with bidders, that should be addressed. Listed below are a number of comments, issues and lessons learned that should be considered as FHA begins preparing for FHA Single Family Mortgage Loan Sale #3.
There were, however, some areas that could be improved:
In SF#2 the winning bidder did flip a small portion of the loans with the consent of counsel. FHA took the position that as long as the winning bidder's counsel held this opinion it was not within FHA's role to question this decision, i.e., the purchaser signed the qualification statement and their counsel advised them that selling to qualified investors was not a "distribution within the meaning of the Securities Act of 1933." For the purposes of future sale, and simply to be cautious, FHA should verify this position.
( Optimization and Small Bidders. One of the issues that was raised with every bidder during the investor phone calls was whether or not they would bid next time. While the overwhelming majority of bidders stated they would bid again, a few indicated that they felt that optimization as currently constructed benefited the large bidders and that unless something was changed they may not be back. While it should be remembered that optimization maximizes proceeds, and normally those that try to tilt bid procedures in their favor or reduce competition generally are not the most aggressive bidders, anything that may retard the effort to create a retail market should be addressed.
Two small bidders stated that they believed that large bidders are able to use the spread make on performing loans to increase the price they pay on non-performing loans (which is what the small bidders were generally interested in). FHA's only concern should be that as many bidders as possible bid so that all bidders will price aggressively, which is what optimization is designed to do. However, if there is a perception that large bidders are unduly benefited by optimization as opposed to their natural advantages, i.e., lower cost of funds, and economies of scale, to the extent that some bidders drop out and competition slackens, the prices submitted by the remaining bidders could drop. Hence, there is a desire on the part of some bidders to further level the playing field, and to the extent that this can be done without eliminating the participation of large bidders FHA should make changes to the current optimization construction.
Several options were suggested, all of which need to be addressed in detail with the financial advisor for SF#3:
1. Create a small investor program. This will likely depress bid prices. Although you cannot keep the large bidders from participating (as lenders or money sources), you will eliminate some, and any decrease in competition by definition should depress prices.
2. Bid on each block separately either open outcry or sealed bid. This also will likely depress prices since most, if not all, of the large bidders will not participate. In addition, several small and mid-sized bidders indicated that it would be very costly to underwrite every single mortgage loan block.
3. Bid on each block separately but allow large bidders to place a floor on the number of blocks they will accept. This is potentially a solution, but Bell Labs has previously indicated that depending on the number of bids and bidders and floor amounts, their is a much higher probability that loans could remain unsold, i.e., too much overlap combined with different floors.
4. Only allow bids to include blocks within a single performance category. The idea is to use the existing five categories of loans (A - E), or create three large categories based on appropriate definitions to result is similar sized categories (about 200 blocks each with about $200 million in UPB), i.e., (a) basically performing, (b) totally nonperforming, and (c) stuff in between. Pool bids could only contain blocks from one category. Several small bidders stated they would much prefer this approach, and since the large bidders could still be assured of winning large blocks they should not oppose this structure.
Continue to provide for direct assignment and endorsement from FHA only to the bidding entity, and not to individual members of a bidding entity. During SF#2 a bidding entity requested that FHA execute powers of attorneys to individual members of a bidding entity, rather than just to the bidding entity as provided by the loan sale agreement, so that the individual members could execute assignments of mortgages and endorsements of notes directly to themselves rather than having to go through a two step process from FHA to the bidding entity then again to the members of bidding entity. FHA allowed this in a supplement under the theory that in this specific instance market competition would not be compromised.
During the market feedback process, one bidder requested that FHA specifically provide in the loan sale agreement for direct closing, or assignment and endorsement to individual members of a bidding entity. To allow this would be to invite the market to actively collude. That is, if no limits were placed on the number of bidders that FHA would close with or help assign and endorse notes to, in theory the entire market could divide up the loans and decide what they want to bid. Hence, a limit would have to be established. However, once you establish a limit you are favoring large bidders over small bidders to a substantial degree. That is, to the extent that several large bidders form a bidding entity, it takes less of them to achieve economies of scale than a group of small bidders. Hence, it is recommended the loan sale agreement not be changed, and this issue dealt with on a request by request basis.